![]() |
Michiel de Haas is PhD student at Wageningen University |
Agricultural commercialization was a key driver of African economic change during the colonial era. Why did some African smallholders adopt cash crops on a considerable scale, while most others were hesitant to do so?
In recent years, debates on the determinants of African development have been dominated by institutional explanations (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2010). However, there is also a current of literature pointing at the importance of ecological factors and resource endowments (Austin, 2008; Tosh, 1980). In this study, we investigate and test the plausible claim that factor endowments crucially shaped the degree to which export crops were adopted by smallholders in colonial tropical Africa.
In recent years, debates on the determinants of African development have been dominated by institutional explanations (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2010). However, there is also a current of literature pointing at the importance of ecological factors and resource endowments (Austin, 2008; Tosh, 1980). In this study, we investigate and test the plausible claim that factor endowments crucially shaped the degree to which export crops were adopted by smallholders in colonial tropical Africa.
![]() |
Kostadis Papaioannou is Post Doc at London School of Economics |
In his seminal contribution, Tosh (1980) made a strong case for a resource endowments perspective on African agricultural commercialization during the colonial era. Tosh argued that different responses of African farmers to export crop cultivation can be explained by the distinction between ‘forest’ and ‘savanna’ areas, in which farmers faced distinct resource endowments. Forest areas have fertile soils and well-distributed rainfall patterns, and are suitable for crops that yield high caloric returns per unit of labour (such as yam, banana) as well as lucrative cash crops (such as coffee and cocoa). Savanna areas, instead, were characterized by a brief growing season during which farmers struggled to secure their subsistence requirements. Not only were labour demands unevenly distributed under such dryer savannah conditions, but farmers also had to rely on drought-resistant but labour intensive grain cultivation, and less lucrative cash crops such as cotton and groundnuts. Consequently, insufficient labour was available to cultivate cash crops without facing food insecurity.
Uganda’s cotton revolution
We conduct an in-depth case study of the ‘cotton revolution’ in colonial Uganda to put Tosh’ argument to the test. Ugandan smallholders, unlike their counterparts elsewhere in Sub-Saharan Africa, adopted cotton on a substantial scale. Cotton was first exported in the early 1900s, and already by the 1920s, Uganda had become the world’s fourth cotton exporter in per capita terms (and 11th in terms of total production). Two common explanations exist in the literature for the exceptional cotton uptake by Ugandan farmers. Firstly scholars arguing from a resource endowment perspective have argued that the success of cotton in Uganda should be attributed to cultivation of the perennial banana by Uganda’s cotton growers. Bananas yielded high caloric returns to labour and left farmers with sufficient labour to cultivate an inedible and labour intensive export crop (Elliot, 1969; Tosh, 1980). However, as illustrated by Figure 1, bananas were only grown in some parts of Uganda, while smallholders in grain growing regions were equally invested in the cultivation of cotton. In other words, this crop-based version of the resource endowments explanation does not hold up to the historical record. Secondly, scholars taking an institutional perspective have argued that Ugandan cotton adoption was the outcome of particularly effective colonial coercion (Hanson, 2003; Young, 1994). Again, however, the explanation does not hold up to the historical evidence: while the most outright Ugandan colonial coercive policies were scaled back during the 1920s, cotton production in this period accelerated.
![]() |
Figure 1: Average annual cotton cultivation in Uganda’s colonial districts (1925-1960) (click to enlarge) |
Figure 2. Bi-modal rainfall and Cotton Planting in Uganda (click to enlarge) |
Rainfall patterns, labour seasonality and cash crop adoption
Firstly, the occurrence of two rainy seasons meant that agricultural labour demands were more smoothly distributed throughout the year, effectively enabling farmers to use more labour to grow crops. Indeed, farmers used the first rainy season to grow food crops, and relegated cotton to the second rainy season. The benefit of spreading out farming operations over two rainy seasons is best illustrated by a comparison between the Teso region of Uganda and northern Côte d’Ivoire (Figure 3). If we assume that the month with the greatest labour input in Figure 3 signifies the potential maximum monthly household labour capacity, this would imply that, because of a more favourable seasonal distribution, farmers in the three Ugandan cases were able to use between 69 and 71 per cent of their annual labour capacity in agriculture, while farmers in Côte d’Ivoire, could only effectively exploit 49 per cent of their labour capacity to produce crops. This gap of just over 20 percentage points may well account for the difference between cotton adoption and rejection.
Figure 3. Intra-annual distribution of labour inputs (left axis) and rainfall (inches, right axis) (click to enlarge) |
Secondly, having two chances to secure subsistence per year mitigated the impact of a single harvest failure, and allowed farmers to take greater risks, such as devoting one of the rainy seasons to the cultivation of an inedible cash crops. We show that farmers relegated cotton to the second rainy season, and hypothesize that the allocation of labour to cotton depended on the degree of food security achieved in the first rainy season.
Food security and cotton cultivation: an empirical
analysis
To test this hypothesis, we perform a panel analysis on a newly constructed, strongly balanced, district-level dataset of cotton acres per capita over a 36 year period (1925-1960). Food crop yield data are impossible to obtain in a smallholder economy with very limited administrative capacity. To proxy for food crop harvests in the first rainy season, we look at rainfall deviation. An extensive body of previous research has shown that rainfall deviation is a reliable estimate of harvest outcomes (Papaioannou, 2017; Papaioannou & De Haas, 2017 for further discussion). Usually, studies look at rainfall on an annual basis, but for our analysis and bimodal context, we take rainfall deviation of the first six months of the year – that is before the planting of cotton. Our panel analysis indicates that rainfall deviation in the first season had a negative impact on subsequent cotton cultivation, suggesting that food security trumped cotton cultivation, and that farmers shifting resources from cotton to food during the second reason to compensate for the disappointing food crop harvest. The effect is stable and highly significant (at the 1% confidence level), and holds up to numerous robustness checks. Interestingly, when we do not find heterogeneity between the grain and banana districts, indicating that rainfall patterns rather than farming systems were decisive to smallholders’ willingness and ability to adopt cotton.
Conclusion
Our study highlights the importance of food security and labour seasonality as important determinants of agricultural commercialization in colonial tropical Africa. We propose that, in a colonial context, bimodality was a close-to-necessary condition for a ‘cash crop revolution’ to occur. At the same time, we are careful not to argue that cash crop adoption can be understood and explained solely by looking at labour seasonality, or even resource endowments more broadly. In this study, we have treated thin markets for credit and food, and limited adoption of agricultural technologies as exogenously given. In reality, of course, such limitations were an outcome of the policies of colonial governments, which operated on a shoestring and were unwilling to invest to any large extent in the agricultural development of their colonies. That resource endowments mattered so much testifies to the poor institutional context in which famers operated.
The working paper can be downloaded here: http://www.ehes.org/EHES_111.pdf
References
Acemoglu, D., and J.A. Robinson. 2010. “Why is Africa poor?” Economic History of Developing Regions 25 (1):21-50.
Austin, G. 2008. “Resources, techniques, and strategies south of the Sahara: revising the factor endowments perspective on African economic development, 1500-2000.” The Economic History Review 61 (3):587-624.
Elliot, C.M. 1969. “Agriculture and economic development in Africa: theory and experience 1880-1914.” In Agrarian change and economic development, edited by E.L. Jones and S.J. Woolf. London: Methuen.
Frankema, Ewout, Jeffrey Williamson, and Pieter Woltjer. 2015. An economic rationale for the African scramble: the commercial transition and the commodity price boom of 1845-1885. National Bureau of Economic Research.
Papaioannou, Kostadis J. 2017. ““Hunger makes a thief of any man”: Poverty and crime in British colonial Asia.” European Review of Economic History 21 (1):1-28.
Papaioannou, Kostadis J., and Michiel de Haas. 2017. “Weather Shocks and Agricultural Commercialization in Colonial Tropical Africa: Did Cash Crops Alleviate Social Distress?” World Development 94:346-365.
Tosh, John. 1980. “The cash-crop revolution in tropical Africa: an agricultural reappraisal.” African Affairs 79 (314):79-94.
Young, Crawford. 1971. “Agricultural policy in Uganda: capability and choice.” In The state of the nations: constraints on development in independent Africa, edited by M.F. Lofchie, 141-164.